Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
In this paper I show that decline in tax revenue from Early Medieval Iraq was mainly due to the fall in soil output. I demonstrate that the fall in soil output, political administration, land tenure and the methods of tax assessment were deeply interrelated. I explain how land tenure, tax administration and political and social structure contributed to the decline in agricultural output, especially in food crops, and why the decline in tax revenue was an important indicator of this economic crisis. In particular, I focus on the incentives and disincentives related to tax collection and administration and, in general, the role of the State in agricultural activity. Taxation was just another form of surplus extraction and reflected the relative power of different social and political groups.
The article argues that any analysis of tax policies must be grounded in the given society’s ‘mode of production’. This is demonstrated through analysis of the political relationship between the Abbasid state and the landlords, and the reasons why certain prominent Muslim jurists between 750 and ca. 900. promoted muqāsama in the Sawād of Iraq. These jurists’ tax policy is explained with reference to Haldon’s concept of the tributary mode of production. It is concluded that according to the jurists, muqāsama favoured a redistribution of surpluses between the state and the landowners which could strengthen relations between the Abbasid state and the powerful landlords in Iraq.
Journal of King Abdulaziz University: Islamic …, 1989
Tax-farming as practiced in Medieval Egypt, Moghul India and the Ottoman empire is considered as a means of resource allocation in an interest-free economy. Material from Turkish archives is utilized to analyze how the system worked by giving signals to the state, in the form of the bids made by the tax-farmers, as to the relative profitability of the various sectors of the economy. In making these bids, the tax-farmers were guided by the expected rates of return in the relevant sectors. Changing profit expectations caused geographical and sectoral shifts of resources. The paper places the historical discussion into perspective by making a brief review of contemporary literature on resource allocation in a modern interest-free Islamic economy. It also notes some negative aspects of the practice of tax-farming.
Transregional and Regional Elites – Connecting the Early Islamic Empire, 2020
This paper aims to identify types of landowners in Lower Iraq, where land was asocial,political and economic issue, especiallyduring the 8 th century. The focus on landholders determines the characterisation of the imperial as well as regional Lower Iraqi elite. It takes into consideration Jewish and Christian landowners (for example, ecclesiastical landed elites in the Nestorian community), Persianl andowners (for example, the dahāqīn who settledi nt he region before the Islamic conquest) and the landed Islamic elites (who are related to the conqueringg roup). With this typology, Is hedl ight not onlyo nt he diversity of landede lites in Lower Iraq but also on the subgroup of Islamic landowners. Defining landownergroups is aprerequisite to the studyofthe interplaybetween local and imperial elites over the course of the 8 th century.Thisperiod is regarded as that of the rise of Islamic elites.Researchers agree these elites werenolongers pecificallyb ound to military functions, ad evelopmentw ith consequences for other landed groups.S ubsequent interplays took place in the context of inter-a nd intra-group relationships. This paper seeks to offer at ypologyo f these interactions in order to understand the relationships and power ratios at stake.
Mamluk Studies Review, 2022
In his impressive study of land tenure in medieval Syro-Egypt, Daisuke Igarashi has pointed out that by the late fourteenth century amirs and sultans increasingly leased land among themselves. These leased lands (mustaʾjarāt) quite often came out of the iqṭāʿ holdings of the sultans' dīwān alkhāṣṣ. The mustaʾjarāt added another facet to the Mamluk real estate and financial industry. An important amir like the atābak al-ʿasākir Shaykhū al-Nāṣirī (d. 1357) is said to have earned an income of over 200,000 dirhams from his iqṭāʿs, amlāks, and mustaʾjarāt. 20 Milk: Milk is private property and as such is usually outside the military taxation system, but of course products of milk land were taxed. There were no restrictions when it came to selling or inheriting milk property, as it was not included in the state systems but registered as individually owned land.
This paper reconstructs the organization and development of factor markets in early medieval Iraq. It shows that from the late Sasanian period on, and accelerating in the early Islamic period, there was a relatively unrestricted functioning of markets for goods, labour, and capital. This stimulated market exchange, associated with growing monetization of the economy, especially in the towns, but also in the countryside, even though coercion remained more pronounced there. We hypothesize that these developments brought economic dynamism but simultaneously increased inequality and furthered the rise of new, powerful elite groups, causing the decline of the same markets
Journal of Agrarian Change, 2009
This article examines the impact of the Arab conquests of the 630s and 640s on rural society and fiscal organization in Egypt. Traditional accounts paint a picture of a seventh-century Egypt from which the aristocracy had largely disappeared and in which Arab rulers and administrators communicated directly with village communities. Drawing upon the testimony of seventh-century documentary papyri, this essay reveals the continued role of Christian elites in administering tax collection and the extent to which the Arab conquerors left agrarian social relations largely undisturbed. Only over the course of the eighth century were indigenous Christian elites sidelined, leading to a number of tax revolts on the part of the Coptic population.
Journal of King Abdulaziz University-Islamic Economics, 1989
15 Gold Coins For Every Student: Musul’s Economic Condition Erbil’s Economic Prosperity From Articial Incubation to Building Ships Ayyubid Financial Organization Caliph As a Member of Futuwwat Organization Abolition of Heavy Taxes in Baghdad Return of Kharaj Tax in Iraq Theft of The State Returning of a Tax of 100,000 Gold Coins To Tax-Payers Innocent Prisoners Set Free Prices Are Falling An International Economic System Supported by Endowments No Taxes For Five Years and other topics.
Explorations in Economic History, 2006
Governments can tax productive activities with either uniform or discriminatory rates among taxpayers. Although discriminatory rates can cause productive inefficiency and require high cost of administration, they can be preferred because of their advantage in distributional flexibility. This paper studies the discriminatory taxation of production in the Fertile Crescent. Using information from the Ottoman tax registers, it examines the basis, distortionary effects, and distributional consequences of discriminatory rates quantitatively. The results challenge widely held beliefs about the basis for discriminatory rates in this region and the Ottoman government's motivation in adapting systems of taxation in newly conquered lands.
Administrative texts from the Sealand I kingdom, a second-millennium polity that emerged in the southern Mesopotamian area lost to Babylonian control during Samsu-iluna’s reign, show that a palatial system of agricultural taxation was in place around the palace town that produced this archive. The imposts collected by the palace are known from the preceding Old Babylonian and the following Middle Babylonian periods, with somewhat differing meanings and methods of recording. The present article examines the Sealand I evidence within the second-millennium Babylonian administrative continuum, in particular the collection of the šibšu, the miksu, and the kisru.
Sociology of Islam, 2019
This essay examines the Islamic land tax (kharāj) during the first wave of the Arab conquests (ca. 12–24/633–50) and the following century and a half. Highlighting the confused state of land tax and landholding, it argues that Sunni jurists incorporated land tax into Islamic law despite the lack of Qurʾānic injunctions and prophetic tradition. In doing so, they drew upon Qurʾānic concepts such as fay’ and ghanīma while reinterpreting a vast body of conquest narratives and traditions that helped present land tax as a bona fide Islamic practice. A major outcome of this juristic discourse of public finance was the recognition of the ruler’s right to discretionary taxation. Just as the jurists emphasized justice and equitable application of tax laws, they also enabled the government to enjoy a wide latitude in its fiscal management without legal backlash. It further allowed the jurists to speak for God and His Prophet.
The Umayyad Empire (661-747 CE), the first dynasty of Islam, reigned nearly ninety years after the so-called Rāshidūn era, was collapsed by the ʿAbbāsid Revolution (AR). After 750, the ʿAbbāsids became the new rulers of the Islamic empire through the culmination of an orchestrated secret campaign lasting more than thirty years and based on popular unfavourable views of the Umayyads. Although extensive research has been carried out on the AR, there have been no studies which try to understand the AR with reference to modern economic and Revolution theories by focusing upon the economic dissatisfaction of the Khurāsānī mawālī who supported the Revolution. The aim of this paper is to discuss the theory that economic disorder in Khurāsān was an important reason for the AR, by focusing on the taxation system in Islam and its abuse in the later Umayyad period (685-747) as well as by evaluating modern Islamic historiography in this perspective. [You may find an extended abstract of this article after the bibliograpy.]
Endeavoring to leave aside dogmatism and mechanically applied Marxist readings, this book examines, from a theoretical point of view, the issue of sociohistorical classification in the medieval Arab-Islamic society. Based on our consideration of feudalism as a mode of production whose essence is the reproduction of productive forces, and as a system that corresponds to serfdom, the form of labor under the feudal mode in which farmers are compelled to transfer surplus production to those who control the land in the form of taxes or in the form of labor rent in kind or in money. When distinguishing between modes of production, little difference emerges between taxation systems and various forms of rent. The Asiatic and tributary modes of production remain, consequently, similar: two sides of the same coin, and they induce little difference from the political, economic and ideological characteristics of the feudal mode of production. As a result, the Arab-Islamic society, then, is feudal according to the type that, in our opinion, was the result of the interaction and intermingling of the four following factors: the tribal confederation, the Islamic religion, the military conquest, and the economic heritage in its material and productive aspect for the peoples of the endemic countries in Western Asia in general. It led to the generation of a feudal mode production that underwent the following historical developmental stages: the tribal phase, the state phase, and the military phase. This coincided with the establishment of the Arab Islamic state, starting with the state of Medina during the reign of Muhammad, passing through the Rashidun, then the Umayyad Caliphate, all the way to the Abbasid Caliphate state.
2007
The subtitle, “Corpus and Context” is intended to emphasize and demonstrate the immeasurably greater value that can be gained from documents when they are examined within the largest relevant corpus manageable, and within the larger context provided by narrative, juridical, and other sources. Unlike papyrologists working on pre-Islamic periods, Arabic papyrologists have available a wealth of narrative sources, opaque though they may sometimes be, which can elucidate the papyri. When documents are examined and interpreted within the larger corpus and context, not only does the edition, translation and understanding of the individual documents increase dramatically, but, also, patterns emerge. The following is drawn from my study of Arabic Agrarian Leases and Tax Receipts from Egypt 765– 1035 A.D./148–427 A.H.2 That larger study is the first systematic edition, translation, and comparison of virtually the entire extant corpus of the identified agricultural leases and tax receipts that...
The article argues that al-Ṭ abarī's History of the Prophets and the Kings provides a free rideranalysis of the decline of Abbasid state power. Al-Ṭ abarī's historical analysis considers state policy on land tax, and religion as a legal norm related to the social contract between the head of state and the landlords. It is concluded that al-Ṭ abarī saw the misāḥ a tax system and 'rule of law' as the principal conditions for imperial rule, and that al-Ṭ abarī's History already provides an answer to modern historians' questions as to why the Abbasid state crumbled, and what role religion played in the political economy.
Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, 2014
Lack of direct evidence on the functioning of factor markets in Sasanian/Late Antique Iraq makes it difficult to present a clear picture of the production side of economy during this period. However, relying on the Talmudic evidence, as well as what is mentioned in the Mādayān ī Hezār Dādestān (MHD), this article aims to provide an idea of factor markets during the Sasanian period, as well as demonstrating the areas where further evidence and research could render better results and allow us to understand the economy of this region in more depth.
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.